Corporate Distress, Credit Default Swaps, and Defaults: Information and Traditional, Contingent, and Empty Creditors

13 Brooklyn Journal of Corporate, Financial & Commercial Law 5-32 (2018)

28 Pages Posted: 2 Jan 2019 Last revised: 27 Feb 2019

See all articles by Henry T. C. Hu

Henry T. C. Hu

University of Texas at Austin - School of Law

Date Written: November 25, 2018

Abstract

Federal securities law seeks to ensure the quality and quantity of information that corporations make publicly available. Informational asymmetries associated with companies in financial distress, but not in bankruptcy, have received little attention. This Article explores some important asymmetries in this context that are curious in their origin, nature, and impact. The asymmetries are especially curious because of the impact of a world with credit default swaps (CDS) and CDS-driven debt “decoupling.”

The Article explores two categories of asymmetries. The first relates to information on the company itself. Here, the Article suggests there is fresh evidence for the belief that troubled companies may prove lax in securities law compliance and for the existing “final period” explanation for such laxity. The Article also offers two new explanations: one based on the requirements for class action certification in Rule 10b-5 litigation and the other based on uncertainties as to private enforceability of “Management’s Discussion and Analysis” disclosure requirements.

Building on the existing analytical framework for decoupling, the Article also examines a less obvious category of asymmetries: “extra-company” informational asymmetries flowing from the CDS and CDS-driven debt decoupling activities of third parties. Such third-party activities can be determinative of a company’s prospects, but reliable public information on the presence, nature, and magnitude of such activities tends to be scant. Here, even the company itself, not just investors, may not have the requisite information, including information on the highly counterintuitive and unusually complex incentives that such third parties may have. Unlike traditional creditors, “empty creditors with a negative economic ownership” as well as certain other buyers of CDS protection can have strong incentives to intentionally cause corporations to go bankrupt even when bankruptcy would make little sense. Such third parties may profit not only from actual defaults on financial covenants—at just the right times—but also from artificially manufacturing “faux” defaults or seizing on real, but largely technical, defaults. The Article examines such CDS and “net short” creditor matters through the lens of four examples. The three most important and recent of these examples have not previously been considered in the academic literature: Norske Skog (a Norwegian lumber company) (involving Blue Crest and GSO Capital Partners), Hovnanian (an American home builder) (involving GSO Capital Partners), and Windstream Services (an American telecommunications company) (involving Aurelius).

Keywords: bankruptcy, credit default swap, covenant, debt decoupling, default, derivative, disclosure, empty creditor with negative economic exposure, net short debt activist, financial distress, hedge fund, information asymmetry, MD&A, 10b-5, securities regulation compliance, troubled companies

JEL Classification: D21, D22, D23, D43, D62, D82, D83, D86, G14, G22, G23, G28, G29, G32, G33, G34, G38, K22, K23, K29,

Suggested Citation

Hu, Henry T. C., Corporate Distress, Credit Default Swaps, and Defaults: Information and Traditional, Contingent, and Empty Creditors (November 25, 2018). 13 Brooklyn Journal of Corporate, Financial & Commercial Law 5-32 (2018), Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3302816

Henry T. C. Hu (Contact Author)

University of Texas at Austin - School of Law ( email )

727 East Dean Keeton Street
Austin, TX 78705
United States
512-232-1373 (Phone)
512-471-6988 (Fax)

Do you have negative results from your research you’d like to share?

Paper statistics

Downloads
727
Abstract Views
3,430
Rank
65,540
PlumX Metrics